Could the equity premium be zero or even negative? In other words, is it possible investors buying and holding stocks for the long run won’t get that extra 3% to 5% over governmentbonds that several studies have found in historical data? Are they better off in fixed-income securities?
Falkenblog had a post making this argument with more than the usual gusto. Main points:
Arithmetic vs. geometric averages: when an index goes from 100 to 200 and back again, the average annual return on an arithmetic basis is 25% (200/2 + 50/2 = 125). The geometric average, which shows 0% change, would seem to be more relevant to the long-term investor.
Survivorship bias: the U.S. had the best stock market in the 20th century –its not a good benchmark for what to expect going forward on average.
After-tax returns: taxes applicable to the equity premium reduce the margin (even in RRSPs since theyjust defer taxes).
Market timing: dollar-weighted returns, reflecting high inflows at peaks and outflows at troughs, are lower than time-weighted returns.
Transactions costs: commissions were about 60 cents/share until the 1975 deregulation and are currently about 2 cents a share (about 0.1%) on average. Plus, mutual funds often had 8.5% fees. . the bid-ask spread will cost you about 0.25% on average.
Add up all these factors, and the equity premium shrinks to zero or worse for the average investor, says Falkenblog.
Food for thought, as they say. Personally, one issue I am wrestling with is: even if the equity premium does exist, how can it be expected to persist? To rephrase, how can onereconcile a positive equity premiumwith the efficient market theorem.
The latter says a systemic opportunity to profit doesnt persist in the stock market because market participants capture such profit opportunities by biding stock prices up or down until the anomaly is eliminated. Yet, the equity premium says there is a systematic opportunity to profit in stocks by buying and holding over the long run.
Ten or fifteen years ago, there werent many books or studies alerting investors to the premium, so not many were responding to it. But now everyone knows about it, so we might expect many investors to have incorporated it into their strategies (or be in the process of doing so). Just look, for example, at how much pension funds and other institutional investors have shifted out of bonds toward equities over the past 10 to 15 years.
The end result may be that stock prices have been bid up relative to long-term fundamentals such that the equity premium will turn out to be close to zero or negative (at least more so forinvestors who buy duringthe maturebullish phases).
Blogs & Comment
Equity premium actually zero or worse?
By Larry MacDonald
Could the equity premium be zero or even negative? In other words, is it possible investors buying and holding stocks for the long run won’t get that extra 3% to 5% over governmentbonds that several studies have found in historical data? Are they better off in fixed-income securities?
Falkenblog had a post making this argument with more than the usual gusto. Main points:
Arithmetic vs. geometric averages: when an index goes from 100 to 200 and back again, the average annual return on an arithmetic basis is 25% (200/2 + 50/2 = 125). The geometric average, which shows 0% change, would seem to be more relevant to the long-term investor.
Survivorship bias: the U.S. had the best stock market in the 20th century –its not a good benchmark for what to expect going forward on average.
After-tax returns: taxes applicable to the equity premium reduce the margin (even in RRSPs since theyjust defer taxes).
Market timing: dollar-weighted returns, reflecting high inflows at peaks and outflows at troughs, are lower than time-weighted returns.
Transactions costs: commissions were about 60 cents/share until the 1975 deregulation and are currently about 2 cents a share (about 0.1%) on average. Plus, mutual funds often had 8.5% fees. . the bid-ask spread will cost you about 0.25% on average.
Add up all these factors, and the equity premium shrinks to zero or worse for the average investor, says Falkenblog.
Food for thought, as they say. Personally, one issue I am wrestling with is: even if the equity premium does exist, how can it be expected to persist? To rephrase, how can onereconcile a positive equity premiumwith the efficient market theorem.
The latter says a systemic opportunity to profit doesnt persist in the stock market because market participants capture such profit opportunities by biding stock prices up or down until the anomaly is eliminated. Yet, the equity premium says there is a systematic opportunity to profit in stocks by buying and holding over the long run.
Ten or fifteen years ago, there werent many books or studies alerting investors to the premium, so not many were responding to it. But now everyone knows about it, so we might expect many investors to have incorporated it into their strategies (or be in the process of doing so). Just look, for example, at how much pension funds and other institutional investors have shifted out of bonds toward equities over the past 10 to 15 years.
The end result may be that stock prices have been bid up relative to long-term fundamentals such that the equity premium will turn out to be close to zero or negative (at least more so forinvestors who buy duringthe maturebullish phases).